Answers
Answers
pages

How much will you earn
if we switch from tax to ground rent

Annual income:

This year
Enter a figure:

Next year
Present system:
Ground rent system:
Difference:

In 5 years
Present system:
Ground rent system:
Difference:

In 50 years
Present system:
Ground rent system:
Difference:

How long until the government's profit from ground rent is equal to, say, the value of all the land in the nation?
Years:

What would you earn now, if your ancestors had chosen ground rent?
Present system:
Ground rent system:

 
Improve the estimates

This page shows how the numbers are calculated. I have entered rough estimates just to get us started. Enter your own preferred numbers for a better estimate. To reset, refresh the page. If the page freezes, try changing the history number to something small (that's where the computer sometimes struggles). (Click here for the underlying theory.)

Productivity:
GDP growth due to unlimited additional tax free work (%)

Imagine that ground rent was set as exactly the same rate as you now pay in tax. You could do the same work, charge the same prices, and pay the same to the government. But once paid you could then do additional work tax free. The result is more employment and cheaper goods and services.
 
Example: Imagine a typical country with 30% tax (income tax plus sales taxes plus other taxes and government fees. To sell a product for $100 it must cost you $70 or less to make. Now imagine the same country with ground rent that cost exactly the same as tax. You would make the same, sell the same, but could then sell extra products for just $70. (In practice, all products would simply be cheaper.) To see how this works, an unintended experiment took place in Denmark in 1969: taxes were frozen for one year due to administrative changes. People saw the chance to do additional untaxed work. That year saw full employment, and production doubled (from 4% to 8%). Production would not double every year of course, so I suggest more modest growth due to permanently cheaper goods.

Land use:
GDP growth due to more efficient use of resources (%)

If land must be paid for then people will only use what they need and sell the rest. (Landowners will be fully compensated.) So all the vacant city lots or under-used land will be better used. This creates a short term jump in growth, due to better resource use. It also creates long term opportunities due to cheaper resources and more investment in industry rather than land.
 
Details: In America in 2013, over 10 percent of homes were empty, and over 50 percent of those were being deliberately kept off the market hoping for prices to rise (source). If these were all sold (to pay ground rents) it would end all housing shortages, If this was repeated across all types of land the whole economy would run more efficiently. In addition, if the supply exceeds the demand, the price of land and housing will go down. This makes everyone feel richer (including the land owners who get a generous lump sum of compensation), and provides a financial safety net for more economic activity, and more money to spend on improving one's prospects. Result: permanently higher economic growth.

Externalities:
GDP growth due to measuring total growth, not spending (%)

At present, it is possible to "make money" through market failure: by restricting choice, by hiding information, or by passing on the costs to someone else ("externalities"). Some of these are very profitable to government because they bring in high taxes. But ground rent does not measure how much money is transferred, only the overall value of society. So governments will no longer have a reason to support damaging industries, and instead focus on real long term value.

Long term:
GDP growth due to longer term thinking (%)

Land values measures not just potential short term profits, but beauty, good neighbours etc. Beauty and good neighbours are measures of potential long term profit: beauty reflects stability and good health, and good neighbours make everything easier. To make money from ground rent, a government must invest in not just short term profit but long term beauty and strength.

Transparency:
GDP growth due to increased transparency (%)

Ground rent is easy for experts to estimate: what is the market value of land? it can be tracked the same way we track share prices. So the value of a government can be assessed by outsiders. Similarly, changes in value due to government policies can also be measured, and as data accumulates, predicted. Government decisions can therefore be checked, increasing accountability, so making bad decisions less likely.

Avoidance:
GDP growth due to no tax avoidance (%)

Land cannot be hidden. So everyone will have to pay. This reduces the bills for those who previously had to pay extra taxes to cover the non-payers. This also means an overall increase in efficiency: tax paying companies have to be more efficient to make the surplus. By removing the less efficient non-paying competitors, more efficient businesses fill the gap.

New business:
GDP growth due to new businesses moving here, and new non-land businesses. (%)

If taxes are ended we can expect, in the short term, an influx of businesses from other nations. In the long term more people will find ways to start businesses that don't use much land (or other natural resources). As they need fewer resources they can expand more rapidly.

Secondary causes of growth

These are effects that can be expected after a few years of primary growth, or after businesses anticipate those effects and act pro-actively.

Infrastructure:
GDP growth due to better roads, networks, etc. (%)

Ground rent allows every major investment to pay for itself. So all needed investment will happen.

Lower costs:
GDP growth due to lower rent and mortgages (%)

Ground rent leads to cheaper mortgages, so investment is cheaper.

Stability:
GDP growth due to smoothing the boom and bust cycle (%)

Without ground rent, people speculate for unearned profit on land. This leads to investment bubbles and crashes. Ground rent removes any profit from land speculation, so it reduces the risk of crashes, so businesses can plan further ahead, enjoy lower interest rates, etc.

GDP growth due to political stability (%)

Without ground rent, governments routinely change their tax and spend policies, and make "reforms" with no agreed way of measuring results. But ground rent reduces a government's role to improving land values. This will tend to make governments more predictable, especially after a few years of data. The role of government changes from "try something, anything" to cautious, reliable long term investment.

Human capital:
GDP growth due to free movement of workers (%)

A stronger, more stable economy with cheaper mortgages and better infrastructure makes it easier to move house. So employers get the best workers available rather then being stuck with whoever is local.

GDP growth due to freeing accountants and entrepreneurs (%)

For a typical business of 60 employees, collecting taxes wastes (one man month per year (details). These are typically the best educated people or people at the top of the business. Ground rent is much simpler: no need to track everything, just pay for land the same way you pay for any other input. So all these brilliant minds and business leaders are free to do useful work instead.

Consumer confidence:
GDP growth due to confidence (due to employment and growth) (%)

The other sources of growth should increase employment as well as wealth, creating greater consumer confidence. I have given this a low number because in the short term the rapid changes might make people nervous (too good to be true?) and in the long term confidence might turn to satisfaction with less. On the other hand, people have never before shown themselves satisfied with less: ambitions merely increase. So feel free to increase this number.

Less distortion:
GDP growth due to no market distortion (%)

At present, some business decisions are taken to avoid tax, rather than to make better products and services. With ground rent the only pressure is to get the best results from resources.

Government efficiency:
GDP growth due to lower government costs (%)

More jobs and more wealth mean lower welfare costs. So more of the ground rents can be invested into productive employment.

IP:
GDP growth due to sharing intellectual property (%)

At present, the only way to guarantee money for intellectual property is to restrict its use. So the whole IP system is a series of barriers and restrictions (or in the case of free software, poverty and begging). However, with ground rent the value of a society can be measured scientifically. (Blockchain technology allows us to track who uses software.) So a company could choose to release software into the wild, and simply collect the wealth that it creates.

E.g. imagine that 100 pieces of genuinely useful software are released, and are used by countless people. Statisticians estimate that society improves its rental value by 1 million dollars thanks to the resulting increased efficiency. Your software is judged to be twice as useful as average. So you gain $20,000 that year, and continue to gain income every year while not wasting any money on selling, or on cosmetic changes with little real benefit. As measurement improves more developers will benefit and so join the system. How much would such a system of free ideas boost economic growth? You decide.

Any other factors? (%)

There is bound to be something I have forgotten. This line simply adds (or takes) a percentage each year. E.g. 2% means the previous total plus 2%, each year.

The baseline

How much do you expect the economy to grow, without ground rent? (%)

This is the baseline growth in GDP, after adjusting for inflation. In most advanced nations growth averages around 2%. In China it can be as much as 10%. I entered the last available figure for the US (2014, 2.4% according to the World Bank). In boom years it is higher, and in recessions it is negative.

How much will your country's population grow each year? (%)

The nation's GDP has to grow by this much for each person's income to stay the same. So when calculating the effect of growth on your income, this amount is ignored. In recent years European populations have grown by around 0.2%, and the USA by around 0.7%.

How much of your "share" of GDP will you get? (%)

If you own no land, or just a small amount (e.g. a single house), increase this figure. If you are a big land owner reduce this figure. But consider investing your big compensation windfall in industry instead of land. If unsure, leave this as 100% (i.e. your current share of national income)

Big numbers

How much money does the nation need? (%)

Paying US land owners the full value of their land will cost $21.2 trillion dollars. The national debt is $18 trillion dollars. Plug in the any number to see how quickly it could be paid off. Anything else you want to pay for?

What if our ancestors had done it?

How many years ago?

Adam Smith recommended ground rents in "The Wealth of Nations" in 1776 (239 years ago), but I have chosen an earlier and better known book: the Bible. According to the five books of Moses, Israel was to get its income from a tithe on land (ten percent of agricultural output). There were no taxes on buildings, or on priests or musicians or midwives or any of the other occupations mentioned. This all changed with the arrival of kings, but the prophet Samuel said (in 1 Samuel 8) the kings were a mistake. So we see that the law of Moses taught ground rent, not tax on work. The books of Moses were written by 600 BC at the latest (2615 years ago). The Bible itself dates Moses at around 1400 BC (3515 years ago: 2015 + 1400 BC).
 
WARNING: LARGE NUMBERS CAN SLOW DOWN THE BROWSER.
 
The calculation
I begin with the lowest possible income: a starvation figure of $400 per year. This is the famous "dollar a day", adjusted for recent inflation. Below that you are probably dead. (All numbers of course are in modern values, they are already adjusted for inflation).
 
Historical growth rates are estimated as lower than today, because of the lack of technology. But not so much lower: technology is also a result of economic opportunity. (When people have money and the possibility to enjoy the fruits of their work, they start to think of ways to make life better.) So for the first 500 years (or half the total years, whichever is shorter) I allow half the modern growth rate, then the full growth rate thereafter.

The underlying theory

How the numbers are calculated

For the precise calculation just look at the code: right click and choose "view source".

A ballpark estimate of what to expect
Current growth is around 2 percent, but history suggests it could easily be three times this, probably more. In recent generations productivity is slumped dramatically, from 2.1% per worker in the baby boomer generation to 0.6% per worker since the 1970s (source; recent figures). (The scale of the slump is usually hidden because more workers entered the work force in that period, mainly women). So three times the current growth is achievable even within the framework of taxes. Far better growth should be possible (according to Adam Smith) if we adopt ground rents.

Growth rates of 10% are normal when a nation is making obvious, clearly understood improvements: e.g. China and India playing catch-up with the west. Perhaps this is a realistic upper limit for how quickly a large society can adapt to change. Ground rents are a new idea for most nations, so mistakes will be made, so my estimated total of all improvements is capped at under two thirds of 10%.

How each number is added
The calculations are simple. I start with the current income then add the percentage in each line, then go to the next line. Then repeat each year. For the precise calculation just look at the code: right click and choose "view source".

For the number that matters, how when ground rent profit can pay off all land, I allow the government to take the same proportion of GDP in ground rent as they currently take in tax. I then calculate the difference between ground rent and the previously expected tax. That profit is put into a compensation pot until it is enough to pay off the land. That is, the land at the price it would have been at that time under a tax system. So even a small home owner can be given a bond worth millions of dollars.

That way, the bond's selling price will be currently the same as the land, and will grow at the same rate land would have grown at until it becomes due for payment, in the year when the government actually has the money.

How ground rent growth is calculated.
To make a fair comparison with taxation (and ensure the government does not go bankrupt) I set ground rent as taking the same proportion of income as it does now. For the USA that is 26% (counting both local and national taxes). I calculate the dollar figure based on 26% of GDP each year (US GDP in 2015 was estimated at 18 trillion). I then increase this by for expected GDP growth each year, comparing growth under tax and growth under ground rent. The difference is profit that is saved (and that profit itself is invested, at the ground rent rate of growth).

The value of all land
According to a study by economist William Larson, in 2015 the value of all land in the USA was $23.0 trillion. $1.8 trillion was owned by the federal government, leaving a bill of $21.2 trillion if every land owner demanded full compensation.

I apply expected growth to this figure each year, and then see when the compensation pot has grown large enough to pay for it all. Note that the GDP at 18 trillion is very close to the land value at 21 trillion. The land value does not include the value of buildings built on the land: these come to roughly the same amount but they still have real economic value regardless of the land beneath them, so can still be sold even if land values crash.

The value of all land may seem low, but this does not include buildings or mineral rights. See the original paper calculating land values for a detailed discussion. Also, some data is from 2009, just after a 25% price crash. But adding 33% only increases the ground rent time pay off period by around two years.

How future land value is calculated.
Land value must go up at the same rate as the stock market, on average. If not, investors would all leave stocks and buy land. This causes the price of land to go up until the profit to be made is the same as from the stock market. But this takes time, so for a short time land will beat stock market growth. This leads to speculative bubbles ad inevitable crashes, where land then gives a lower return. Eventually it catches up and the boom-bust cycle continues.

Stocks represent shares in businesses of all kinds, or in other words, shares in all the wealth in the nation. So they should go up at the same rate as GDP. In reality they are volatile as well (for the same speculative reason as land), and tend to go up slightly slower than GDP. But for simplicity I will be generous and assume they rise at the same rate. (If we choose a lower rate then ground rent becomes profitable to land owners even sooner!)

So land values are expected to rise at the same rate as GDP over the long term.

AnswersAnswers